Showing posts with label asset overvaluation. Show all posts
Showing posts with label asset overvaluation. Show all posts

Sunday, April 24, 2011

Why the Fed Must Cut Short It's QE2 Inflation Gamble

from Zero Hedge:

The Federal Reserve has lost all credibility on Wall Street, and most of the American public with the absolute refusal to recognize the dire effects on asset prices that QE2 has created. But the refusal is part of the problem. It reinforces the wide spread belief of investors that the Fed is out of touch with reality, and that they sit in their Ivory Tower implementing an exceedingly loose monetary policy, with the stated goal of inflating asset prices.

The Fed has refused to even acknowledge the possibility (rather than the indisputable facts) that not only have they inflated selected asset prices like S&P 500, the Dow indexes, but they also have inflated asset prices like food, energy, and clothing which would actually hurt the economy and consumers (See Chart).


Needed – Housing and Wage Inflation

Remember, overall inflation is actually being artificially under-reported by the numbers because housing and wages are not inflating. These are the two actual groups of assets that Americans in reality need the Fed to inflate. But Fed’s policies have been unable to help and seem to essentially be hurting the housing sector, as higher everyday living costs with stagnant wages tend to reduce disposable income and resources that could be otherwise allocated to saving towards a down payment to purchase a house, improving the real estate sector of the economy.

Inflation Exported Would Come Back To Haunt 

Furthermore, since most of these asset prices are priced in dollar, the fed has exported dire and extreme inflationary pressures on an already precariously balanced inflationary picture in the emerging market economies from China to India.

It is the proverbial throwing of jet fuel on a barbeque for most of the economies. Yes, Bernanke is right that these countries had inflationary problems before based upon their undervaluing currencies. Nevertheless, this is how their economies have been set up in the global trade role that has been 30 years in the making.

These countries just couldn`t revalue their currencies near enough to still keep their role as exporting, cheap labor manufacturers, without sending the entire region into a 10-year depression which would bring the entire world into a depression not seen since the Great Depression.

Unmanageable Inflation Elsewhere

Given the fact that these manufacturing exporting countries cannot meaningfully revalue their currencies, they are basically stuck with an endemic higher level of inflation compared with the developed economies, but it is still manageable. Now, with the US`s persistently loose monetary policies exacerbated by QE2, raising input costs for commodities used in abundance by these manufacturing, cheap labor economies like Oil, Copper, Cotton, and Iron Ore (See Chart), these policies are exporting additional inflationary pressures to these developing economies.


This results in making what would be a manageable level of inflation in China of around 3.5 to 4% an unmanageable level of inflation at 5.5 to 6%, and maybe even higher as the full effects of the inflation of commodity asset prices have not yet fully been incorporated and manifested in the Chinese manufacturing economy.

Long Live the Inflation Trade

The other area where Ben Bernanke`s stubbornness of acknowledging the effects of QE2 on food and energy prices, i.e., the rise in prices is due strictly to demand reasons, Middle East tensions, and product shortages and in no part to a loose monetary policy which encourages traders to make the following trade:
  1. Loose monetary policy is dollar negative (printing money, currency devaluation, etc). 
  2. Commodities like Oil, Gold, Silver, Wheat, Corn, Cotton, Copper are Dollar negative Hedges  
  3. Therefore, put on the following trade: Short the dollar, and go long commodities.
This is the famous inflation trade is has been going on and off for the past 10 years by fund managers around the world. This trade has been in the investing 101 handbook for 50 plus years. And the fact that Ben Bernanke never admits to knowing about these trade dynamics in the marketplace, and how his policy initiate of QE2 actually encourages, facilitates and even mandates that fund managers around the world put on this very trade is beyond a rational explanation.

Inflationary Effects Are Transitory?

In addition, it is even more incredulous of Bernanke and his failure to acknowledge any role whatsoever for the feds function in these higher commodity prices when their stated goal is to in fact inflate asset prices. Whenever he is interviewed about this very question he always uses the standard response that inflationary pressures are not due to the recent Fed policy of QE2.

I guess these are assets that the Federal Reserve has expressly forbidden traders to inflate. However, Bernanke also adds that these inflationary effects are transitory in nature--he has been saying “transitory” for over 6 months now. How long does it take for ‘transitory” to become “stuck in the economy, and cannot get rid of without a massive rate hike sledgehammer”?

Fed Out of Touch with Reality

It is starting to sound like a broken record, and it is completely divorced from the facts in the marketplace, or the facts on the ground for those not in the Ivory Tower. It is this main street denial that has reinforced the notion that Bernanke and his dovish colleagues with their incessant soft selling of inflation in their comments regarding inflation questions every week that they are out of touch with reality.

This “fed out of touch with reality” notion only goes to reinforce the very “Inflation /Currency Devaluation Trade” causing traders to pile even more capital into shorting the US Dollar and going long Commodities because it is only going to get worse down the line. This is what is referred to as inflation expectations.

Dovish Fed Undermines The Dollar 

The fed policies regarding QE2 are not near as damaging for the US Dollar as traders perceptions of the Fed policy of QE2, and judging by the rise in Silver alone will tell you, traders perceptions of QE2 is extremely negative. And that old adage perception is reality takes hold and traders do far more damage to the US Dollar than any actual currency devaluation due to QE2 by going heavily short the currency. Traders and their perceptions right now are what is really hurting the US Dollar and Bernanke has failed to realize this fact.

Another interesting question for Bernanke and his Dovish colleagues, and it appears that even the more hawkish members of the Fed are still to dovish in their market comments regarding inflation. Probably because they all are in the upper income bracket on a percentage basis compared with the average US consumer, and are largely immune to the ridiculous six month rise in food and energy prices felt by the average American citizen.

The Fed can change all that on the 27th of April with either a cutting short of QE2, or an equally hawkish wording of the fed statement with a nod towards tightening sooner than previously indicated in past policy statement wording.

Everyone Worries Except the Fed

The Fed might ask themselves the following question:
  • How come at every Speech where there is a question and answer session that you are asked about inflation?
  • Or how come every reporter when interviewing a fed member asks them about their role in causing inflation around the world and how this is contributing to political and social instability in emerging economies?
  • Is this just by coincidence, all these reporters and questions revolving around inflation effects? The answer is that these questions are being asked for a reason, and that alone is a problem for the fed.
Another question for Bernanke is how come every other country is worried about inflation, including developed economy neighbor Europe, while the US doesn`t have an inflation problem? It seems the US is the only country in the entire world where inflation isn`t a problem? Does this seem logical?  And if it is in fact the case, how long do you think it will stay this way, where the entire globe is experiencing inflation pressures but the US has a “transitory” inflation problem?

When Transitory Turns Self-Fulfilling

The problem for the Fed is that this goes beyond current inflationary effects in the economy, but future expectations of inflation in the economy. And none of these are transitory in nature once they get embedded in the psyche of investors and consumers. The only way they were doused in 2008 when they were at these exact levels was a near historic crash in the financial and housing markets.

Absent of some similarly extreme deflationary event, inflation and expectations of inflation are only going to feed on themselves and become even more firmly entrenched in the economy, negatively reinforcing investors and consumer’s asset allocation and spending habits.

This all becomes self fulfilling in nature, and the real nasty part about inflation is if you don`t head it off early, once it gets even a little momentum, it becomes much more difficult to control and manage. This is where the fed is right now; they are at the cusp of losing control of their handle on inflation with their incredibly dovish stance towards inflation.

End the Denial or Lose on Inflation

Bernanke and the current Federal Reserve Board have a credibility problem both with Wall Street traders and the American population. The sooner Ben Bernanke acknowledges his role in causing inflation, the better off we will be in fighting the battle of inflation. The longer the denial routine of “transitory’ responses continues, the increased chance that Bernanke loses what shred of remaining credibility he has on the inflation issue.

Then, the inflation battle is essentially lost without equally devastating policy responses that are almost similarly as bad as the inflation effects, i.e., you have to send the economy into a recession with an abundance of tightening measures that completely destroys growth to get a handle on prices.

Needed - Hawkish & Cut Short of QE2

Again, the Fed and Bernanke can change all this on the 27th of April, failure to do so basically dooms Bernanke`s legacy to be remembered by the initial moniker put on him when he initially was chosen as Alan Greenspan`s successor, when he was commonly referred to as “Helicopter Ben”!

During his first six months on the job as Fed chairman, he did everything possible to dispel such a label, but he has more than made up for that period during the last six months regarding his outright refusal to acknowledge the exceedingly negative side effects revolving around out of control food and energy prices related to his QE2 Initiative.

The average American citizen cannot withstand another two months of “Asset Inflating” on behalf of the Fed, enough is enough, time to cut the QE2 policy initiative short.

Friday, April 1, 2011

Looking to the End of QE2

John Hussman gave me this perspective on the likely outcome of QE2 as it reaches an end:

Last week's stock market advance placed prevailing conditions firmly back to an overvalued, overbought, overbullish, rising-yields syndrome that has historically been hostile for stocks, on average. Our investment stance considers not only these factors, but also reflects the (present) accommodative stance of monetary policy, as well as a broad range of measures such as market internals, credit spreads, and economic statistics. I've noted before that as rules of thumb go, "the trend is your friend" historically performs better, with much smaller drawdowns, than "don't fight the Fed" (regardless of how that rule is defined operationally). While the market tends to perform better when both are true, the exception is the overvalued, overbought, overbullish, rising-yields syndrome, which is uniformly negative regardless of the random subset of historical data one examines. There is certainly a tendency for "unpleasant skew" featuring a persistent series of marginal new highs for some period of time, but on average, those are ultimately overwhelmed by steep and abrupt losses that finally clear this syndrome.

It's important to recognize that our present investment stance reflects these observable conditions, and is not driven by our views about the underlying state of mortgage debt, fiscal challenges, economic forecasts, expectations of credit strains, or any view about the appropriateness of Fed intervention. We do try to look ahead to some of the risks that may emerge in the quarters ahead, but our investment stance is not driven by this analysis. If we can clear some component of the observable, hostile syndrome of market conditions - probably either the overbought or overbullish feature - without a substantial breakdown in market internals (which would take us "out of the frying pan and into the fire"), we expect to quickly establish a moderately constructive investment stance. Our concerns regarding larger economic risks can be sufficiently expressed by holding a continued line of index put options to defend against any unanticipated continuation, but again, barring a breakdown of market internals (which would suggest a larger and possibly more durable shift toward investor risk aversion), I expect that clearing the present, hostile syndrome will be sufficient to accept a greater exposure to market fluctuations.
Our longer-term analysis remains that the S&P 500 is priced to achieve poor 10-year total returns, but that in itself doesn't resolve into the requirement to carry a persistently defensive position over the short- and intermediate-term. Even if the market remains overvalued and economic risks persist for a long time, we do expect that the "ensemble" solution to the "two data sets" problem we struggled with in recent years will result in more frequent periods of moderate investment exposure than we observed during that period. Still, our dominant investment horizon remains the full market cycle, so our usual "anti-marketing" applies - the Hussman Funds are not appropriate for investors who have a strong desire to track market fluctuations or whose investment horizon is shorter than a full bull-bear cycle. That said, even for investors who prefer to track the market up and down to a reasonable degree, it is worth emphasizing that combining a long-only approach with less correlated approaches that still compete well over the full cycle can significantly improve the return/risk profile of the portfolio over time.
QE2 - Apres Moi, le Deluge
Last week, a number of Fed officials came out in tandem with essentially the same message - the Fed's policy of quantitative easing is likely to end with QE2. It's important to think carefully about the implications of this for the markets. My impression is that investors are still in something of a "momentum" mentality both with respect to the market and the overall economy, and it's not clear that they've pieced out the extent to which this has been reliant on various stimulus measures that are now drawing to a close.
It is clear that the effect of QE2 has not been to lower interest rates, or to materially expand credit. Rather, QE2 has been built on two blunt forces. The first is that increasing the stock of non-interest bearing money in the economy toward $2.4 trillion, all of which has to be held by somebody, the Fed has created a market environment that has raised the prices and lowered the returns on all competing assets in order to accommodate that equilibrium. As asset prices are bid up, their expected future returns fall, and the process stops at the point where on a risk-adjusted basis, no asset is expected to achieve returns that compete meaningfully with cash (at least over some horizon of say, a year or two). The second force has been purely rhetorical. The opening salvo in QE2 was Bernanke's public endorsement of risk-taking in the Washington Post. Strikingly, he has seemed to eagerly take credit for the speculation in the stock market, particularly in small cap stocks, while denying any culpability for the commodity hoarding and dollar weakness that predictably results from driving real short-term interest rates to negative levels.
In our view, quantitative easing has been a reckless policy, not only because it has fueled what Dallas Fed president Richard Fisher calls "extraordinary speculative activity," but because aside from a burst of short-term optimism, the historical evidence is clear that fluctuations in stock prices have very little impact on real spending (the so-called wealth effect is on the order of 0.03-0.05% for every 1% change in stock prices). People consume off of perceived permanent income, not off of fluctuations in the prices of volatile assets. Now, it's true that QE2 has probably been good for a fraction of 1% in additional GDP, which should be sustained over a period of a year or two, and though we haven't observed real activity or actual industrial production that matches the optimism of survey-based measures such as the ISM indices, it's clear that some pent-up demand was released. Still, the links between monetary base expansion, stock values, and GDP growth are tenuous at best. The most predictable outcome was commodity hoarding, where our expectations have been fully realized, with awful consequences for the world's poor, not to mention for geopolitical stability.
So for our part, we'd be happy to see the termination of QE simply because it is misguided, reckless policy. In contrast, most of the Fed officials pulling back on their enthusiasm for QE argue along the lines that "the economy is strong enough now to do without it," which is unfortunate because it leaves the door open to continue this sort of lunacy should the economy weaken again. A few quotations from various Fed officials last week:
Charles Evans (Chicago Fed) "Following through on that to the tune of $600 billion, like we've said, I think is appropriate. I personally don't see as many needs for a further amount, as I probably thought last fall."
James Bullard (St. Louis Fed): "The economy is looking pretty good. It is still reasonable to review QE2 in the coming meetings, especially this April meeting, and see if we want to decide to finish the program or to stop a little bit short."
Charles Plosser (Philadelphia Fed): " If this forecast is broadly accurate, then monetary policy will have to reverse course in the not-too-distant future and begin to remove the massive amount of accommodation it has supplied to the economy. Failure to do so in a timely manner could have serious consequences for inflation and economic stability in the future. I don't think that is necessarily imminent, but we have to be very careful we don't get behind the curve. I worry about us getting behind the curve. "
Richard Fisher (Dallas Fed): "In essence what we have done as a central bank is to monetize the entire US debt through the end of June. Had I been a voter last year, which I am this year, I would have joined Hoenig and would have voted against what is known as QE2. In my opinion, no further accommodation is needed after June -- either by tapering off the bottom of the purchases of Treasuries, or by adding another tranche of purchases outright. In my view it is unlikely that we will have or need more accommodation by the central bank. I think we've done our job."
While the possibility of ending QE2 early may come up in the FOMC's April meeting, I doubt that the Fed will stop short. Regardless of the lack of meaningful "wealth effect" from stocks to GDP in the historical data, it's clear that Bernanke views a speculative stock market as a good thing, and my impression is that he would consider the risk of disappointing the markets as too great. Instead, the Fed will have enough on its hands simply removing the expectation of the market for QE3, not to mention telegraphing the potential for the Fed to eventually reverse course.
Still, barring a surprise early-conclusion to QE2, there are two important issues for the market as we look ahead to gradual changes in Fed policy.
First, what happens when QE2 is complete? From our standpoint, it is incontrovertible that the primary factor behind the market's recent advance has been speculation based on the belief, explicitly encouraged by Bernanke, that the Fed would provide a backstop for risk-taking. Investors clearly took Bernanke at his word. But without yet another round of QE, not to mention the potential for an unwinding of existing QE, a decline in speculative enthusiasm will likely have the identical effect as an increase in risk aversion.
Second, how likely is it that economic growth will be successfully "handed off" to the private sector as fiscal policy tightens and monetary policy becomes less aggressive? It is clear that the economy is enjoying some surface economic progress - the most notable being a gradual drop in new claims for unemployment. But the real fiscal "cliff" for states and municipalities doesn't hit until about mid-year, which is the same time that QE2 comes off. What we're observing at present is decidedly still fiscal- and monetary-induced growth. It is not enough that the data have improved gradually. The real question is whether it would have, or will, improve without that stimulus.
My intent is not to argue strongly that the economy cannot continue to expand as fiscal and monetary stimulus comes off, but instead to at least ask why this should be expected as a foregone conclusion. On the basis of leading indices of economic activity, we observe more indications of economic slowing worldwide than we observe growth. Moreover, strong periods of employment growth have historically been preceded by high, not low, real interest rates. This is far from a perfect relationship, but it is clear that historically, high real interest rates are far more indicative of strong demand for credit, new investment, and new employment than low real interest rates are.
The belief that low real interest rates are helpful is the result of confusing the demand curve with equilibrium itself. Yes, strictly from the demand curve, lower real interest rates are associated with greater demand for capital investment and so forth. But if we want growth, then what we really desire is a persistent outward shift in the demand curve. We want increased desire for real investment and employment at every level of real interest rates. Meanwhile, on the supply side, higher real interest rates help to induce a shift from consumption toward savings that can be directed to finance that new investment. In equilibrium, then, what generally precedes strong economic growth is an upward movement in real rates. Trying to engineer low real rates, which is what the Fed seems to want, is an attempt to move along the existing demand curve, which can never, in itself, be the source of sustained growth, and harms savers at the same time (as the Fed's Richard Fisher observed last week, it only works to "continue the injustice against the virtuous.")
On the employment front, it is important to recognize that while the annual growth of non-farm payrolls averaged about 2% and higher prior to the 1990's, each cycle of U.S. economic expansion and recession has resulted in slower and slower long-term employment growth. The chart below shows what I would characterize as a series of "vicious cycles" - particularly the most recent experience. On the chart, business cycles move counter-clockwise, with expanding year-over-year employment growth gradually improving the 10-year average, followed by a slowdown and eventually a contraction in employment growth that since the 1960's has dragged long-term employment growth to progressively lower levels in each successive business cycle. Given the high level of unemployment, the "mean-reversion benchmark" would normally be about 200,000 jobs monthly. We should sustain that for a few more months, but the likely effect of reduced policy stimulus should not be ignored looking out further.
The bottom of the chart is where we are at present. In my view, the poor performance of the U.S. economy from an employment standpoint cannot be separated from the Fed's attempts, for more than a decade, to make easy monetary policy a substitute for the accumulation of real savings and investment. All that we've done is to finance a huge stream of consumption, which we have quietly paid for by selling off claims on our assets and future output to foreign savers such as China and Japan. The Fed has surely helped us to build that indebtedness without pain from an interest rate standpoint, but the volume of claims is increasingly onerous. Unlike Japan, which has a high debt-to-GDP ratio but finances the bulk of it with its own savings, our debt is increasingly external, which means that someone else has a claim to our future output. Speculating and consuming off of cheap credit may feel better than saving, but the long-term results are profoundly different.
The problem for the financial markets here, in my view, is that the benefits of the speculation are now largely behind us. Our valuation models do assume that long-term growth in GDP and earnings will persist at the same roughly 6.3% peak-to-peak growth rate across economic cycles that has characterized the earnings channel for nearly a century. Yet given the level of stock valuations to normalized earnings - which better reflect the long-term stream of cash flows that investors can expect to receive - our present 10-year total return estimate for the S&P 500 is only about 3.4% annually (and to Mish, yes, the historical skew to these returns easily includes zero in the confidence interval).
None of this rules out further positive market returns over shorter periods, and we remain willing to accept moderate periodic exposures even here, provided that we can clear some component of the overvalued, overbought, overbullish, rising-yields syndrome we presently observe. But as Charles Dow said a century ago, "to understand values is to understand the meaning of the market." Occasional prospects for moderate exposure notwithstanding, I continue to view the long-term prospects for equities as weak. This is largely because we continue to rely on band-aids and overwhelming policy interventions to keep interest rates low and market valuations elevated, in preference to lower valuations (and commensurately higher interest rates and prospective equity returns) which would offer proper incentives to save and allocate capital for productive long-term uses.
Market Climate
As of last week, the Market Climate for stocks reflected a continued hostile syndrome of conditions that holds us to a well hedged investment stance in both the Strategic Growth Fund and the Strategic International Equity Fund. In bonds, the Market Climate remained characterized by relatively neutral yield levels as well as neutral yield pressures. The Strategic Total Return Fund continues to carry a duration of just over 4 years, with about 10% of assets allocated to precious metals shares. As I've noted before, very shallow corrections in gold followed by moves approaching the $1500 level would be consistent with increasing hazard risk, so I would expect that we'll tend to lighten our holdings on any "range expansion" moves in precious metals shares (large leaps in price that have a wider overall range than that of preceding weeks). For now, we're moderately constructive in both bonds and precious metals. We are defensive in stocks, but that would change on a decline sufficient to clear overbought, overbullish conditions without being severe enough to materially damage market internals (which would signal more a more significant shift toward investor risk aversion). As always, we'll respond to changes in market conditions as they emerge.