"No very deep knowledge of economics is usually needed for
grasping the immediate effects of a measure; but the task of economics
is to foretell the remoter effects, and so to allow us to avoid such
acts as attempt to remedy a present ill by sowing the seeds of a much
greater ill for the future."
– Ludwig von Mises
We heard from Bernanke today with his Jackson Hole speech. Not
quite the fireworks of his speech ten years ago, but it does offer us a
chance to contrast his thinking with that of another Federal Reserve
official who just published a paper on the Dallas Federal Reserve
website. Bernanke laid out the rationalization for his policy of ever
more quantitative easing. But how effective is it? And are there
unintended consequences we should be aware of? Why is it that the
markets seem to positively salivate over the prospect of additional QE?
Quickly, I will be doing an inaugural "Fireside Chat" with Barry
Ritholtz on Tuesday, September 11 at 1 PM Eastern. This webinar will be
hosted by my friends at Altegris Investments and will be available to
accredited investors and financial professionals. If you have already
registered with the Mauldin Circle (and are in the US), you will shortly
be receiving an invitation to attend. If you have not, I invite you to
go to
www.mauldincircle.com
and register today, so you can hear Barry and me discuss the latest
news and, of course, touch on the election and what it means for
investors. Now, let's delve into quantitative easing.
No one really expected any fireworks in Bernanke's speech, and
he fully met expectations. We got the obligatory rationalization for
what passes as current Fed policy. The part the markets wanted to hear
is highlighted below for you.
"… As we assess the benefits and costs of alternative policy
approaches, though, we must not lose sight of the daunting economic
challenges that confront our nation. The stagnation of the labor market
in particular is a grave concern not only because of the enormous
suffering and waste of human talent it entails, but also because
persistently high levels of unemployment will wreak structural damage on
our economy that could last for many years.
"Over the past five years, the Federal Reserve has acted to
support economic growth and foster job creation, and it is important to
achieve further progress, particularly in the labor market. Taking due
account of the uncertainties and limits of its policy tools,
the
Federal Reserve will provide additional policy accommodation as needed
to promote a stronger economic recovery and sustained improvement in
labor market conditions in a context of price stability."
Did that last sentence ring any bells? Let's look at his Jackson
Hole speech in August of 2010 (hat tip Joan McCullough).
"We will continue to monitor economic developments closely and
to evaluate whether additional monetary easing would be beneficial.
In
particular, the Committee is prepared to provide additional monetary
accommodation through unconventional measures if it proves necessary,
especially if the outlook were to deteriorate significantly. The
issue at this stage is not whether we have the tools to help support
economic activity and guard against disinflation. We do. As I will
discuss next, the issue is instead whether, at any given juncture, the
benefits of each tool, in terms of additional stimulus, outweigh the
associated costs or risks of using the tool."
Standard-issue Fed speech. This has been his theme for the last
four years, if memory serves. In every speech he gives a nod to the
proposition that he and his colleagues are seriously analyzing the
effects of Fed quantitative easing policies to make sure the benefits
outweigh the costs. I have not heard a serious critique or exposition
from Bernanke of those risks, as of yet. But we did get a victory lap
from him this year, as he took credit for the economy and the stock
market. Let's go back to the speech (again, my bold):
"Importantly, the effects of LSAPs [large-sized asset purchases]
do not appear to be confined to longer-term Treasury yields.
"Notably, LSAPs have been found to be associated with
significant declines in the yields on both corporate bonds and MBS. The
first purchase program, in particular, has been linked to substantial
reductions in MBS yields and retail mortgage rates.
"LSAPs also
appear to have boosted stock prices,
presumably both by lowering discount rates and by improving the economic
outlook; it is probably not a coincidence that the sustained recovery
in US equity prices began in March 2009, shortly after the FOMC's
decision to greatly expand securities purchases.
This effect is potentially important, because stock values affect both consumption and investment decisions."
I missed the part where Congress gave the Fed a third mandate,
to target the stock market. But Bernanke not only takes credit for the
stock market, he points out that the rebound in the housing market is
also due to Fed policy, because it fostered lower mortgage rates. Which
it did. But let's also remember that it was Fed policy that helped
create the housing bubble to begin with. Which I don't remember Bernanke
taking credit for, even though he was on the Fed then and up to his
eyeballs in supporting that policy.
Joan McCullough, in her own irreverent style, gave us a few must-read paragraphs this afternoon:
"And then [Bernanke] has the
sand to make a public
comment that stocks go up when he prints money because discount rates
have gone down and the economic outlook has improved on account of it?
This is what makes the hot dogs run stocks up the flagpole when The
Bernank saddles up? Better economic outlook? Amazing.
"Lemme go back now and give you the reality version of the Bernanke portfolio balance channel.
"He relieves investors of the lowest risk-bearing vehicles,
forcing them to seek yield elsewhere and at the same time, take on
increasing risk. Until, increasingly yield-starved as this 'balancing'
is relentless, they arrive at the door of the stock market. And
mindlessly take the plunge. Because they have no choice. They are now
balls-to-the-walls exposed. Waiting for the next round of QE.
"Because Lord knows, the first two did jack. Of course, in the
earliest part of his diatribe today, he does make a case as to how the
lower rates worked some magic on the economy, although exactly how much
is difficult to pinpoint. As usual, too, he also blames the fiscal
intransigence as well as tight credit conditions at the banks for
holding back the beauty of his genius from working its total magic."
Let me get this straight. If I design a tax policy that somehow
might benefit "the rich," I am immediately labeled a Luddite supply-side
theorist, as well as heartless, etc.
It is pretty standard for Keynesian economics professors to
deride supply-side economics and what they call trickle-down economics.
Cutting taxes on the rich will translate into a better economy and jobs?
They scoff at such notions, as do almost all the liberal elements in
politics.
Which brings us to this delicious irony. While they abhor
trickle-down economic policy, they love what is in effect trickle-down
monetary policy.
Bernanke explicitly targets a policy of helping the rich (those
who own stocks) and then suggests that the result of making the rich
richer will be increased consumption and final demand. Which will
somehow trickle down to the guys and gals in the unemployment line.
The paper posted at the Dallas Fed, which we will take up in the
next section, specifically notes that QE has a special benefit for "the
senior management of banks in particular." That amounts to a thunderous
indictment of the crony capitalism of current policy. It's hard to
argue that there is much trickle down with that particular unintended
consequence!
The paper also notes that "… it is also worth asking whether, to
some degree, this [rising income inequality] might be another
unintended consequence of ultra easy monetary policy. Not only has the
share of wages (in total factor income) been declining in many
countries, but the rising profit share has been increasingly driven by
the financial sector [which explicitly benefits from QE]. It seems to
defy common sense that at one point 40 percent of all US corporate
profits (value added?) came from this single source."
Understand, I am NOT arguing that an easy monetary policy
doesn't have an effect on stocks and that it will have an effect on the
overall economy. There is clearly a wealth effect. It is just that
almost all (not quite but almost) of the arguments that one can make for
trying to boost the stock market are the same that one uses for arguing
that tax cuts also increase consumption and the wealth effect.
As a short preview to next week's letter, Christina Romer and
her husband and fellow UC Berkeley professor, David H. Romer, published a
paper in the normally staid
American Economic Review which noted
that tax cuts and increases have a multiplier of about 3. (Christina
Romer was Obama's chair of the Council of Economic Advisors, from the
beginning of his term until
[very] shortly after this paper was published.)
Most mainstream economists and liberals (or those who are both,
as in the case of Krugman) make fun of the wealth and economic effects
from tax cuts and ignore Romer's work, or try to show why it does not
apply to eliminating the Bush tax cuts, which they oppose (and which,
interestingly, the Romers' study specifically included). But then they
turn around and ask for more of what is effectively the same thing in
monetary policy. It will be great fun to watch the contorted positions
they have to assume in trying to suggest this is not the case. Kind of
like the contorted position that Clint Eastwood was referring to last
night. They will use anecdotal "evidence" and allegories without
actually referring to academic analysis or peer-reviewed studies. It is
much easier to make an assertion than to actually demonstrate its
validity in the real world. Their antics will serve to drive me nuts,
however.
Note that I am not saying that either tax policy or monetary
policy should be evaluated in the harsh glare of immediate economic
results. Taxes have to be evaluated on more than just their effect on
the economy, and monetary policy has to be judged on more than the
immediate reaction of the markets.
Which brings us to the more serious part of this letter. Let's start with a review of a quote from Bastiat:
"In the economic sphere an act, a habit, an institution, a law
produces not only one effect, but a series of effects. Of these effects,
the first alone is immediate; it appears simultaneously with its cause;
it is seen. The other effects emerge only subsequently;
they are not seen; we are fortunate if we
foresee them.
"There is only one difference between a bad economist and a good one: the bad economist confines himself to the
visible effect; the good economist takes into account both the effect that can be seen and those effects that must be
foreseen.
"Yet this difference is tremendous; for it almost always happens
that when the immediate consequence is favorable, the later
consequences are disastrous, and vice versa. Whence it follows that the
bad economist pursues a small present good that will be followed by a
great evil to come, while the good economist pursues a great good to
come, at the risk of a small present evil."
- From an essay by Frédéric Bastiat in 1850, "That Which Is Seen and That Which Is Unseen"
William R. White is currently the chairman of the Economic
Development and Review Committee at the OECD in Paris. He was previously
Economic Advisor and Head of the Monetary and Economic Department at
the Bank for International Settlements in Basel, Switzerland. He is
clearly no economic lightweight, nor is he an ideologue. When he writes,
attention must be paid. (
http://williamwhite.ca/content/biography)
And he has written a rather pointed indictment of Federal
Reserve monetary policy, which has been published on the Dallas Federal
Reserve website:
http://dallasfed.org/assets/documents/institute/wpapers/2012/0126.pdf
Basically, he looks at the unintended consequences of
quantitative easing and concludes that there are limits to what central
banks can do, and negative consequences if policies are too easy for too
long. He notes later in the essay that:
"Stimulative monetary policies are commonly referred to as
'Keynesian'. However, it is important to note that Keynes himself was
not convinced of the effectiveness of easy money in restoring real
growth in the face of a Deep Slump. This is one of the principal
insights of the General Theory."
I am going to quote him at length in the next few pages. I hope
that it intrigues you enough that you will want to go and read the paper
yourself. This is not just dry theory. If QE is maintained for too
long, then those of us in the "cheap seats" will have to deal with the
consequences. Let me note that there are some 126 footnotes. I would
recommend at least keeping up with them, as I found the "extra"
commentary to often be very enlightening. This is a well-written paper
that avoids the all-too-typical verbal garbage that passes for economics
writing these days.
Let's start with his introduction:
"The central banks of the advanced market economies (AME's) have
embarked upon one of the greatest economic experiments of all time –
ultra easy monetary policy. In the aftermath of the economic and
financial crisis which began in the summer of 2007, they lowered policy
rates effectively to the zero lower bound (ZLB). In addition, they took
various actions which not only caused their balance sheets to swell
enormously, but also increased the riskiness of the assets they chose to
purchase. Their actions also had the effect of putting downward
pressure on their exchange rates against the currencies of Emerging
Market Economies (EME's). Since virtually all EME's tended to resist
this pressure, their foreign exchange reserves rose to record levels,
helping to lower long term rates in AME's as well. Moreover, domestic
monetary conditions in the EMEs were eased as well. The size and global
scope of these discretionary policies makes them historica
lly
unprecedented. Even during the Great Depression of the 1930's, policy
rates and longer term rates in the most affected countries (like the US)
were never reduced to such low levels.
"In the immediate aftermath of the bankruptcy of Lehman Brothers
in September 2008, the exceptional measures introduced by the central
banks of major AME's were rightly and successfully directed to restoring
financial stability. Interbank markets in particular had dried up, and
there were serious concerns about a financial implosion that could have
had important implications for the real economy. Subsequently, however,
as the financial system seemed to stabilize, the justification for
central bank easing became more firmly rooted in the belief that such
policies were required to restore aggregate demand6 after the sharp
economic downturn of 2009. In part, this was a response to the
prevailing orthodoxy that monetary policy in the 1930's had not been
easy enough and that this error had contributed materially to the
severity of the Great Depression in the United States.7
"However, it was also due to the growing reluctance to use more
fiscal stimulus to support demand, given growing market concerns about
the extent to which sovereign debt had built up during the economic
downturn. The fact that monetary policy was increasingly seen as the
'only game in town' implied that central banks in some AME's intensified
their easing even as the economic recovery seemed to strengthen through
2010 and early 2011. Subsequent fears about a further economic
downturn, reopening the issue of potential financial instability, gave
further impetus to 'ultra easy monetary policy'.
"From a Keynesian perspective, based essentially on a one period
model of the determinants of aggregate demand, it seemed clearly
appropriate to try to support the level of spending. After the recession
of 2009, the economies of the AME's seemed to be operating well below
potential, and inflationary pressures remained subdued. Indeed, various
authors used plausible versions of the Taylor rule to assert that the
real policy rate required to reestablish a full employment equilibrium
(and prevent deflation) was significantly negative. Such findings were
used to justify the use of non standard monetary measures when nominal
policy rates hit the ZLB.
"There is, however, an alternative perspective that focuses on
how such policies can also lead to unintended consequences over longer
time periods. This strand of thought also goes back to the pre War
period, when many business cycle theorists focused on the cumulative
effects of bankâ€createdâ€credit on the supply side of the economy. In
particular, the Austrian school of thought, spearheaded by von Mises
and Hayek, warned that credit driven expansions would eventually lead to
a costly misallocation of real resources ('malinvestments') that would
end in crisis. Based on his experience during the Japanese crisis of the
1990's, Koo (2003) pointed out that an overhang of corporate investment
and corporate debt could also lead to the same result (a 'balance sheet
recession').
"Researchers at the Bank for International Settlements have
suggested that a much broader spectrum of credit driven 'imbalances',
financial as well as real, could potentially lead to boomâ€bust
processes that might threaten both price stability and financial
stability. This BIS way of thinking about economic and financial crises,
treating them as systemic breakdowns that could be triggered anywhere
in an overstretched system, also has much in common with insights
provided by interdisciplinary work on complex adaptive systems. This
work indicates that such systems, built up as a result of cumulative
processes, can have highly unpredictable dynamics and can demonstrate
significant non linearities. The insights of George Soros, reflecting
decades of active market participation, are of a similar nature."
And then White anticipates his conclusion:
"One reason for believing this is that monetary stimulus,
operating through traditional ('flow') channels, might now be less
effective in stimulating aggregate demand than previously. Further,
cumulative ('stock') effects provide negative feedback mechanisms that
over time also weaken both supply and demand. It is also the case that
ultra easy monetary policies can eventually threaten the health of
financial institutions and the functioning of financial markets,
threaten the 'independence' of central banks, and can encourage
imprudent behavior on the part of governments. None of these unintended
consequences is desirable. Since monetary policy is not 'a free lunch',
governments must therefore use much more vigorously the policy levers
they still control to support strong, sustainable and balanced growth at
the global level."
White anticipates the objection that ultra-easy monetary policies clearly had a positive effect early on.
"The force of these arguments might seem to lead to the
conclusion that continuing with ultra easy monetary policy is a
thoroughly bad idea. However, an effective counter argument is that such
policies avert near term economic disaster and, in effect, 'buy time'
to pursue other policies that could have more desirable outcomes. Among
these policies might be suggested more international policy coordination
and higher fixed investment (both public and private) in AME's. These
policies would contribute to stronger aggregate demand at the global
level. This would please Keynes. As well, explicit debt reduction,
accompanied by structural reforms to redress other 'imbalances' and
increase potential growth, would make remaining debts more easily
serviceable. This would please Hayek. Indeed, it could be suggested that
a combination of all these policies must be vigorously pursued if we
are to have any hope of achieving the 'strong, sustained and ba
lanced
growth' desired by the G 20. We do not live in an 'eitherâ€or' world.
"The danger remains, of course, that ultra easy monetary policy
will be wrongly judged as being sufficient to achieve these ends. In
that case, the 'bought time' would in fact have been wasted. In this
case, the arguments presented in this paper then logically imply that
monetary policy should be tightened, regardless of the current state of
the economy, because the near term expected benefits of ultra easy
monetary policies are outweighed by the longer term expected costs.
Undoubtedly this would be very painful, but (by definition) less painful
than the alternative of not doing so. John Kenneth Galbraith touched
upon a similar practical conundrum some years ago when he said
"'Politics is not the art of the possible. It is choosing between the unpalatable and the disastrous'.
"This might well be where the central banks of the AME's
[advanced-market economies] are now headed, absent the vigorous pursuit
by governments of the alternative policies suggested above."
White then launches into a long litany of unintended and
undesirable consequences of maintaining an easy monetary policy too
long, some of which we can clearly see developing now. He particularly
notes problems with the shadow banking system and the effects of low
interest rates on insurance companies (and, I would add, pensions!).
"What are the implications of ultra easy monetary policy for
governments? One technical response is that it could influence the
maturity structure of government debt. With a positively sloped yield
curve, governments might be tempted to rely on ever shorter financing.
This would leave them open to significant refinancing risks when
interest rates eventually began to rise. Indeed, if the maturity
structure became short enough, higher rates to fight inflationary
pressure might cause a widening of the government deficit sufficient to
raise fears of fiscal dominance. In the limit, monetary tightening might
then raise inflationary expectations rather than lower them."
"A more fundamental effect on governments, however, is that it
fosters false confidence in the sustainability of their fiscal position…
Koo, Martin Wolf of the Financial Times, and others are undoubtedly
right in suggesting that a debt driven private sector collapse should
normally be offset by public sector stimulus. What cannot be forgotten,
however, is the suddenness with which market confidence can be lost, and
the fact that the Japanese situation is highly unusual in a number of
ways."
If interest rates were to rise in the US to more normal levels,
the deficit would explode under current spending and tax policies,
destroying whatever policy solutions are reached next year.
There is no easy way to exit from current policies, and the
longer one waits the more difficult it will get. This is true in the US,
Europe, and Japan. It is part and parcel of the Endgame. And this is
the defining challenge of our time, and especially in the US as we
approach the coming election. I will attempt to outline the key economic
issues next week.